Les Inscriptions à la Bibliothèque sont ouvertes en
ligne via le site: https://biblio.enp.edu.dz
Les Réinscriptions se font à :
• La Bibliothèque Annexe pour les étudiants en
2ème Année CPST
• La Bibliothèque Centrale pour les étudiants en Spécialités
A partir de cette page vous pouvez :
Retourner au premier écran avec les recherches... |
Management science / Wallace, J Hopp . Vol. 56 N° 3Management science: a Journal of the institute for operations research and the management sciencesMention de date : Mars 2010 Paru le : 18/07/2010 |
Dépouillements
Ajouter le résultat dans votre panierCharitable motives and bidding in charity auctions / Peter T. L. Popkowski Leszczyc in Management science, Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010)
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 399-413
Titre : Charitable motives and bidding in charity auctions Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Peter T. L. Popkowski Leszczyc, Auteur ; Michael H. Rothkopf, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 399-413 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Charity auctions Charitable motives Controlled field experiments Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Research on bidding in auctions has generally relied on the assumption of self-interested bidders. This work relaxes that assumption in the context of charity auctions. Because understanding charitable motives has important implications for auction design and charities' fundraising strategies, this study investigates bidders' specific types of charitable motives and the strength of these motives. We carry out three controlled field experiments consisting of real-life auctions conducted on a local Internet auction site. We use a novel design in which we simultaneously run charity and noncharity auctions for identical products and vary the percentage donated to charity. Results show that auctions with proceeds donated to charity lead to significantly higher selling prices, a result due to a higher bidding by bidders with charitable motives rather than to increased bidder entry. We also find that increased prices only occur when the charitable donation is a percentage of the auction revenue, and that a fixed charitable donation associated with each auction has no effect on prices. Furthermore, we find that prices are increasing in the percentage donated to charity. We find considerable support for a model of voluntary shill-like bidding, where charitable bidders try to increase proceeds in charity auctions. We also find that auctions with 25% of revenue donated to charity had higher net revenue than noncharity auctions. Hence, companies may be able to use charity auctions as part of a corporate social responsibility strategy and at the same time increase profitability even though they donate part of the proceeds to charity. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Charitable motives and bidding in charity auctions [texte imprimé] / Peter T. L. Popkowski Leszczyc, Auteur ; Michael H. Rothkopf, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 399-413.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 399-413
Mots-clés : Charity auctions Charitable motives Controlled field experiments Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Research on bidding in auctions has generally relied on the assumption of self-interested bidders. This work relaxes that assumption in the context of charity auctions. Because understanding charitable motives has important implications for auction design and charities' fundraising strategies, this study investigates bidders' specific types of charitable motives and the strength of these motives. We carry out three controlled field experiments consisting of real-life auctions conducted on a local Internet auction site. We use a novel design in which we simultaneously run charity and noncharity auctions for identical products and vary the percentage donated to charity. Results show that auctions with proceeds donated to charity lead to significantly higher selling prices, a result due to a higher bidding by bidders with charitable motives rather than to increased bidder entry. We also find that increased prices only occur when the charitable donation is a percentage of the auction revenue, and that a fixed charitable donation associated with each auction has no effect on prices. Furthermore, we find that prices are increasing in the percentage donated to charity. We find considerable support for a model of voluntary shill-like bidding, where charitable bidders try to increase proceeds in charity auctions. We also find that auctions with 25% of revenue donated to charity had higher net revenue than noncharity auctions. Hence, companies may be able to use charity auctions as part of a corporate social responsibility strategy and at the same time increase profitability even though they donate part of the proceeds to charity. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 414-429
Titre : Navel gazing : Academic inbreeding and scientific productivity Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Hugo Horta, Auteur ; Francisco M. Veloso, Auteur ; Rócio Grediaga, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 414-429 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Research and development Organizational studies Productivity Education systems Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : The practice of having Ph.D. graduates employed by the university that trained them, commonly called “academic inbreeding,” has long been suspected to be damaging to scholarly practices and achievement. Despite this perception, existing work on academic inbreeding is scarce and mostly exploratory. Using data from Mexico, we find evidence that, first, academic inbreeding is associated with lower scholarly output. Second, the academically inbred faculty is relatively more centered on its own institution and less open to the rest of the scientific world. This navel-gazing tendency is a critical driver of its reduced scientific output when compared with noninbred faculties. Third, we reveal that academic inbreeding could be the result of an institutional practice, such that these faculty members contribute disproportionately more to teaching and outreach activities, which allows noninbred faculty members to dedicate themselves to the research endeavor. Thus, a limited presence of inbreds can benefit the research output of noninbreds and potentially the whole university, but a dominantly inbred environment will stifle productivity, even for noninbreds. Overall, our analysis suggests that administrators and policy makers in developing nations who aim to develop a thriving research environment should consider mechanisms to limit this practice. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Navel gazing : Academic inbreeding and scientific productivity [texte imprimé] / Hugo Horta, Auteur ; Francisco M. Veloso, Auteur ; Rócio Grediaga, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 414-429.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 414-429
Mots-clés : Research and development Organizational studies Productivity Education systems Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : The practice of having Ph.D. graduates employed by the university that trained them, commonly called “academic inbreeding,” has long been suspected to be damaging to scholarly practices and achievement. Despite this perception, existing work on academic inbreeding is scarce and mostly exploratory. Using data from Mexico, we find evidence that, first, academic inbreeding is associated with lower scholarly output. Second, the academically inbred faculty is relatively more centered on its own institution and less open to the rest of the scientific world. This navel-gazing tendency is a critical driver of its reduced scientific output when compared with noninbred faculties. Third, we reveal that academic inbreeding could be the result of an institutional practice, such that these faculty members contribute disproportionately more to teaching and outreach activities, which allows noninbred faculty members to dedicate themselves to the research endeavor. Thus, a limited presence of inbreds can benefit the research output of noninbreds and potentially the whole university, but a dominantly inbred environment will stifle productivity, even for noninbreds. Overall, our analysis suggests that administrators and policy makers in developing nations who aim to develop a thriving research environment should consider mechanisms to limit this practice. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc Revenue management with strategic customers / Kinshuk Jerath in Management science, Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010)
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 430-448
Titre : Revenue management with strategic customers : Last-minute selling and opaque selling Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Kinshuk Jerath, Auteur ; Serguei Netessine, Auteur ; Senthil K. Veeraraghavan, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 430-448 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Distribution channels Competition Revenue management Strategic consumer behavior Rational expectations Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Companies in a variety of industries (e.g., airlines, hotels, theaters) often use last-minute sales to dispose of unsold capacity. Although this may generate incremental revenues in the short term, the long-term consequences of such a strategy are not immediately obvious: More discounted last-minute tickets may lead to more consumers anticipating the discount and delaying the purchase rather than buying at the regular (higher) prices, hence potentially reducing revenues for the company. To mitigate such behavior, many service providers have turned to opaque intermediaries, such as Hotwire.com, that hide many descriptive attributes of the service (e.g., departure times for airline tickets) so that the buyer cannot fully predict the ultimate service provider. Using a stylized economic model, this paper attempts to explain and compare the benefits of last-minute sales directly to consumers versus through an opaque intermediary. We utilize the notion of rational expectations to model consumer purchasing decisions: Consumers make early purchase decisions based on expectations regarding future availability, and these expectations are correct in equilibrium. We show that direct last-minute sales are preferred over selling through an opaque intermediary when consumer valuations for travel are high or there is little service differentiation between competing service providers, or both; otherwise, opaque selling dominates. Moreover, contrary to the usual belief that such sales are purely mechanisms for disposal of unused capacity, we show that opaque selling becomes more preferred over direct last-minute selling as the probability of having high demand increases. When firms randomize between opaque selling and last-minute selling strategies, they are increasingly likely to choose the opaque selling strategy as the probability of high demand increases. When firms with unequal capacities use the opaque selling strategy, consumers know more clearly where the opaque ticket is from and the efficacy of opaque selling decreases. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Revenue management with strategic customers : Last-minute selling and opaque selling [texte imprimé] / Kinshuk Jerath, Auteur ; Serguei Netessine, Auteur ; Senthil K. Veeraraghavan, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 430-448.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 430-448
Mots-clés : Distribution channels Competition Revenue management Strategic consumer behavior Rational expectations Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Companies in a variety of industries (e.g., airlines, hotels, theaters) often use last-minute sales to dispose of unsold capacity. Although this may generate incremental revenues in the short term, the long-term consequences of such a strategy are not immediately obvious: More discounted last-minute tickets may lead to more consumers anticipating the discount and delaying the purchase rather than buying at the regular (higher) prices, hence potentially reducing revenues for the company. To mitigate such behavior, many service providers have turned to opaque intermediaries, such as Hotwire.com, that hide many descriptive attributes of the service (e.g., departure times for airline tickets) so that the buyer cannot fully predict the ultimate service provider. Using a stylized economic model, this paper attempts to explain and compare the benefits of last-minute sales directly to consumers versus through an opaque intermediary. We utilize the notion of rational expectations to model consumer purchasing decisions: Consumers make early purchase decisions based on expectations regarding future availability, and these expectations are correct in equilibrium. We show that direct last-minute sales are preferred over selling through an opaque intermediary when consumer valuations for travel are high or there is little service differentiation between competing service providers, or both; otherwise, opaque selling dominates. Moreover, contrary to the usual belief that such sales are purely mechanisms for disposal of unused capacity, we show that opaque selling becomes more preferred over direct last-minute selling as the probability of having high demand increases. When firms randomize between opaque selling and last-minute selling strategies, they are increasingly likely to choose the opaque selling strategy as the probability of high demand increases. When firms with unequal capacities use the opaque selling strategy, consumers know more clearly where the opaque ticket is from and the efficacy of opaque selling decreases. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc Optimal commodity trading with a capacitated storage asset / Nicola Secomandi in Management science, Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010)
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 449-467
Titre : Optimal commodity trading with a capacitated storage asset Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Nicola Secomandi, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 449-467 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Inventory Production Policies Dynamic programming Markov Finance Asset pricing Real options Industries Petroleum Natural gas Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : This paper considers the so-called warehouse problem with both space and injection/withdrawal capacity limits. This is a foundational problem in the merchant management of assets for the storage of commodities, such as energy sources and natural resources. When the commodity spot price evolves according to an exogenous Markov process, this work shows that the optimal inventory-trading policy of a risk-neutral merchant is characterized by two stage and spot-price dependent basestock targets. Under some assumptions, these targets are monotone in the spot price and partition the available inventory and spot-price space in each stage into three regions, where it is, respectively, optimal to buy and inject, do nothing, and withdraw and sell. In some cases of practical importance, one can easily compute the optimal basestock targets. The structure of the optimal policy is nontrivial because in each stage the merchant's qualification of high (selling) and low (buying) commodity prices in general depends on the merchant's inventory availability. This is a consequence of the interplay between the capacity and space limits of the storage asset and brings to light the nontrivial nature of the interface between trading and operations. A computational analysis based on natural gas data shows that mismanaging this interface can yield significant value losses. Moreover, adapting the merchant's optimal trading policy to the spot-price stochastic evolution has substantial value. This value can be almost entirely generated by reacting to the unfolding of price uncertainty, that is, by sequentially reoptimizing a model that ignores this source of uncertainty. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Optimal commodity trading with a capacitated storage asset [texte imprimé] / Nicola Secomandi, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 449-467.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 449-467
Mots-clés : Inventory Production Policies Dynamic programming Markov Finance Asset pricing Real options Industries Petroleum Natural gas Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : This paper considers the so-called warehouse problem with both space and injection/withdrawal capacity limits. This is a foundational problem in the merchant management of assets for the storage of commodities, such as energy sources and natural resources. When the commodity spot price evolves according to an exogenous Markov process, this work shows that the optimal inventory-trading policy of a risk-neutral merchant is characterized by two stage and spot-price dependent basestock targets. Under some assumptions, these targets are monotone in the spot price and partition the available inventory and spot-price space in each stage into three regions, where it is, respectively, optimal to buy and inject, do nothing, and withdraw and sell. In some cases of practical importance, one can easily compute the optimal basestock targets. The structure of the optimal policy is nontrivial because in each stage the merchant's qualification of high (selling) and low (buying) commodity prices in general depends on the merchant's inventory availability. This is a consequence of the interplay between the capacity and space limits of the storage asset and brings to light the nontrivial nature of the interface between trading and operations. A computational analysis based on natural gas data shows that mismanaging this interface can yield significant value losses. Moreover, adapting the merchant's optimal trading policy to the spot-price stochastic evolution has substantial value. This value can be almost entirely generated by reacting to the unfolding of price uncertainty, that is, by sequentially reoptimizing a model that ignores this source of uncertainty. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc The impact of misalignment of organizational structure and product architecture on quality in complex product development / Bilal Gokpinar in Management science, Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010)
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 468-484
Titre : The impact of misalignment of organizational structure and product architecture on quality in complex product development Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Bilal Gokpinar, Auteur ; Wallace J. Hopp, Auteur ; Seyed M. R. Iravani, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 468-484 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : New product development Product architecture Organizational structure Complex networks Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Product architecture and organizational communication play significant roles in complex product development efforts. By using networks to characterize both product structure and communication patterns, we examine the impact of mismatches between these on new product development (NPD) performance. Specifically, we study the vehicle development process of a major auto company and use vehicle quality (warranty repairs) as our NPD performance metric. Our empirical results indicate that centrality in a product architecture network is related to quality according to an inverted-U relationship, which suggests that vehicle subsystems of intermediate complexity exhibit abnormally high levels of quality problems. To identify specific subsystems in danger of excessive quality problems, we characterize mismatches between product architecture and organizational structure by defining a new metric, called coordination deficit, and show that it is positively associated with quality problems. These results deepen our understanding of the impact of organizational structure and product architecture on the NPD process and provide tools with which managers can diagnose and improve their NPD systems. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] The impact of misalignment of organizational structure and product architecture on quality in complex product development [texte imprimé] / Bilal Gokpinar, Auteur ; Wallace J. Hopp, Auteur ; Seyed M. R. Iravani, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 468-484.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 468-484
Mots-clés : New product development Product architecture Organizational structure Complex networks Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Product architecture and organizational communication play significant roles in complex product development efforts. By using networks to characterize both product structure and communication patterns, we examine the impact of mismatches between these on new product development (NPD) performance. Specifically, we study the vehicle development process of a major auto company and use vehicle quality (warranty repairs) as our NPD performance metric. Our empirical results indicate that centrality in a product architecture network is related to quality according to an inverted-U relationship, which suggests that vehicle subsystems of intermediate complexity exhibit abnormally high levels of quality problems. To identify specific subsystems in danger of excessive quality problems, we characterize mismatches between product architecture and organizational structure by defining a new metric, called coordination deficit, and show that it is positively associated with quality problems. These results deepen our understanding of the impact of organizational structure and product architecture on the NPD process and provide tools with which managers can diagnose and improve their NPD systems. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 485-494
Titre : Package size decisions Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Oded Koenigsberg, Auteur ; Rajeev Kohli, Auteur ; Ricardo Montoya, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 485-494 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Package size Pricing Product design Product policy Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : We describe a model examining how a firm might choose the package size and price for a product that deteriorates over time. Our model considers four factors: (1) the usable life of the product, (2) the rates at which consumers use the product, (3) the relation between package size and the variable cost of the product, and (4) the minimum quantities consumers seek to consume for each dollar they spend (we call these reservation quantities). We allow heterogeneity in the usage rates and reservation quantities for the consumers. We show that when the cost increases as a linear or convex function of the package size, the firm should make packages of the smallest possible size. Smaller packages reduce waste and allow consumers to more closely match their purchases with desired consumption. This in turn allows the firm to charge a higher unit price and also sell more unit volume. The results imply that in a market with multiple package sizes (produced by the same or competing firms), at least one of the packages must have the smallest possible size, provided the fixed cost of making the product is sufficiently low. For concave cost functions, the firm may find it optimal to make larger than smallest-size packages. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Package size decisions [texte imprimé] / Oded Koenigsberg, Auteur ; Rajeev Kohli, Auteur ; Ricardo Montoya, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 485-494.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 485-494
Mots-clés : Package size Pricing Product design Product policy Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : We describe a model examining how a firm might choose the package size and price for a product that deteriorates over time. Our model considers four factors: (1) the usable life of the product, (2) the rates at which consumers use the product, (3) the relation between package size and the variable cost of the product, and (4) the minimum quantities consumers seek to consume for each dollar they spend (we call these reservation quantities). We allow heterogeneity in the usage rates and reservation quantities for the consumers. We show that when the cost increases as a linear or convex function of the package size, the firm should make packages of the smallest possible size. Smaller packages reduce waste and allow consumers to more closely match their purchases with desired consumption. This in turn allows the firm to charge a higher unit price and also sell more unit volume. The results imply that in a market with multiple package sizes (produced by the same or competing firms), at least one of the packages must have the smallest possible size, provided the fixed cost of making the product is sufficiently low. For concave cost functions, the firm may find it optimal to make larger than smallest-size packages. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc Vertical flexibility in supply chains / Wallace J. Hopp in Management science, Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010)
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 495-502
Titre : Vertical flexibility in supply chains Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Wallace J. Hopp, Auteur ; Seyed M. R. Iravani, Auteur ; Wendy Lu Xu, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 495-502 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Supply chain Flexibility Capacity investment Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Jordan and Graves (Jordan, W. C., S. C. Graves. 1995. Principles on the benefits of manufacturing process flexibility. Management Sci. 41(4) 577–594) initiated a stream of research on supply chain flexibility, which was furthered by Graves and Tomlin (Graves, S. C., B. T. Tomlin. 2003. Process flexibility in supply chains. Management Sci. 49(7) 907–919), that examined various structures for achieving horizontal flexibility within a single level of a supply chain. In this paper, we extend the theory of supply chain flexibility by considering placement of vertical flexibility across multiple stages in a supply chain. Specifically, we consider two types of flexibility—logistics flexibility and process flexibility—and examine how demand, production, and supply variability at a single stage impacts the best stage in the supply chain for each type of flexibility. Under the assumptions that margins are the same regardless of flexibility location, capacity investment costs are the same within and across stages, and flexibility is limited to a single stage of logistics (process) flexibility accompanied with necessary process (logistics) flexibility, we show that both types of flexibility are most effective when positioned directly at the source of variability. However, although expected profit increases as logistics flexibility is positioned closer to the source of variability (i.e., downstream for demand variability and upstream for supply variability), locating process flexibility anywhere except at the stage with variability leads to the same decrease in expected profit. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Vertical flexibility in supply chains [texte imprimé] / Wallace J. Hopp, Auteur ; Seyed M. R. Iravani, Auteur ; Wendy Lu Xu, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 495-502.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 495-502
Mots-clés : Supply chain Flexibility Capacity investment Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Jordan and Graves (Jordan, W. C., S. C. Graves. 1995. Principles on the benefits of manufacturing process flexibility. Management Sci. 41(4) 577–594) initiated a stream of research on supply chain flexibility, which was furthered by Graves and Tomlin (Graves, S. C., B. T. Tomlin. 2003. Process flexibility in supply chains. Management Sci. 49(7) 907–919), that examined various structures for achieving horizontal flexibility within a single level of a supply chain. In this paper, we extend the theory of supply chain flexibility by considering placement of vertical flexibility across multiple stages in a supply chain. Specifically, we consider two types of flexibility—logistics flexibility and process flexibility—and examine how demand, production, and supply variability at a single stage impacts the best stage in the supply chain for each type of flexibility. Under the assumptions that margins are the same regardless of flexibility location, capacity investment costs are the same within and across stages, and flexibility is limited to a single stage of logistics (process) flexibility accompanied with necessary process (logistics) flexibility, we show that both types of flexibility are most effective when positioned directly at the source of variability. However, although expected profit increases as logistics flexibility is positioned closer to the source of variability (i.e., downstream for demand variability and upstream for supply variability), locating process flexibility anywhere except at the stage with variability leads to the same decrease in expected profit. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 503-518
Titre : Randomization vs. selection : How to choose in the absence of preference? Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Eric Danan, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 503-518 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Randomization Selection Money pump Indifference Noncomparability Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Decision makers sometimes have to choose between alternative options about which they have no preference: either they judge the options equally valuable (indifference) or they have no judgment about their relative value (noncomparability). Choosing randomly is generally considered a natural way to deal with such situations. This paper shows, however, that systematic randomization between noncomparable options may lead to a chain of decisions resulting in monetary losses (a money pump). Furthermore, these losses can be avoided by deliberately selecting one of the noncomparable options instead of randomizing. Thus, randomization among noncomparable options is costly relative to deliberate selection. On the other hand, randomization among indifferent options is costless relative to deliberate selection. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Randomization vs. selection : How to choose in the absence of preference? [texte imprimé] / Eric Danan, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 503-518.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 503-518
Mots-clés : Randomization Selection Money pump Indifference Noncomparability Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Decision makers sometimes have to choose between alternative options about which they have no preference: either they judge the options equally valuable (indifference) or they have no judgment about their relative value (noncomparability). Choosing randomly is generally considered a natural way to deal with such situations. This paper shows, however, that systematic randomization between noncomparable options may lead to a chain of decisions resulting in monetary losses (a money pump). Furthermore, these losses can be avoided by deliberately selecting one of the noncomparable options instead of randomizing. Thus, randomization among noncomparable options is costly relative to deliberate selection. On the other hand, randomization among indifferent options is costless relative to deliberate selection. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 519-535
Titre : Innovation in business groups Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Sharon Belenzon, Auteur ; Tomer Berkovitz, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 519-535 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Business groups Innovation Patents Internal capital markets Knowledge spillovers Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Using novel data on European firms, this paper investigates the relationship between business groups and innovation. Controlling for various firm characteristics, we find that group affiliates are more innovative than standalones. We examine several hypotheses to explain this finding, focusing on group internal capital markets and knowledge spillovers. We find that group affiliation is particularly important for innovation in industries that rely more on external funding and in groups with more diversified capital sources, consistent with the internal capital markets hypothesis. Our results suggest that knowledge spillovers are not the main driver of innovation in business groups because firms affiliated with the same group do not have a common research focus and are unlikely to cite each other's patents. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Innovation in business groups [texte imprimé] / Sharon Belenzon, Auteur ; Tomer Berkovitz, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 519-535.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 519-535
Mots-clés : Business groups Innovation Patents Internal capital markets Knowledge spillovers Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Using novel data on European firms, this paper investigates the relationship between business groups and innovation. Controlling for various firm characteristics, we find that group affiliates are more innovative than standalones. We examine several hypotheses to explain this finding, focusing on group internal capital markets and knowledge spillovers. We find that group affiliation is particularly important for innovation in industries that rely more on external funding and in groups with more diversified capital sources, consistent with the internal capital markets hypothesis. Our results suggest that knowledge spillovers are not the main driver of innovation in business groups because firms affiliated with the same group do not have a common research focus and are unlikely to cite each other's patents. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc Component-based technology transfer in the presence of potential imitators / Jiong Sun in Management science, Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010)
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 536-552
Titre : Component-based technology transfer in the presence of potential imitators Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Jiong Sun, Auteur ; Laurens G. Debo, Auteur ; Sunder Kekre, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 536-552 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Technology transfer Cost-saving potential Technology imitation Sourcing Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Technology transfer to low-cost locations offers global firms an opportunity to reduce their variable costs involved in serving emerging markets. However, such moves may also make imitation by local competitors easier. As a consequence, technology transfer may create competition in the local market. We introduce component-based technology transfer for the global firm as a means to deter or accommodate the imitators' entry, recognizing that components may differ in technological complexity. By choosing a subset of components to transfer, the global firm's decision has an impact not only on the imitators' fixed entry costs, but also on postentry competition based on variable costs. Our research identifies two different types of deterrence strategies—the barrier-erecting strategy and the market-grabbing strategy. In the former deterrence strategy, the global firm retains enough component technology in the home country to make the potential imitator's fixed entry costs so high that it is not worthwhile entering. In the latter deterrence strategy, the global firm transfers enough component technology to the emerging market, reducing the global firm's variable cost to make the potential imitator's revenues so low that it is not worthwhile entering. Which deterrence strategy the global firm should employ depends on the degree to which geographical proximity reduces imitation costs and the degree of differentiation between the local firm's and the global firm's products. Some other interesting and counterintuitive results arise. For example, it may benefit a global firm to transfer less technology for products with a higher emerging market potential. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Component-based technology transfer in the presence of potential imitators [texte imprimé] / Jiong Sun, Auteur ; Laurens G. Debo, Auteur ; Sunder Kekre, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 536-552.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 536-552
Mots-clés : Technology transfer Cost-saving potential Technology imitation Sourcing Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : Technology transfer to low-cost locations offers global firms an opportunity to reduce their variable costs involved in serving emerging markets. However, such moves may also make imitation by local competitors easier. As a consequence, technology transfer may create competition in the local market. We introduce component-based technology transfer for the global firm as a means to deter or accommodate the imitators' entry, recognizing that components may differ in technological complexity. By choosing a subset of components to transfer, the global firm's decision has an impact not only on the imitators' fixed entry costs, but also on postentry competition based on variable costs. Our research identifies two different types of deterrence strategies—the barrier-erecting strategy and the market-grabbing strategy. In the former deterrence strategy, the global firm retains enough component technology in the home country to make the potential imitator's fixed entry costs so high that it is not worthwhile entering. In the latter deterrence strategy, the global firm transfers enough component technology to the emerging market, reducing the global firm's variable cost to make the potential imitator's revenues so low that it is not worthwhile entering. Which deterrence strategy the global firm should employ depends on the degree to which geographical proximity reduces imitation costs and the degree of differentiation between the local firm's and the global firm's products. Some other interesting and counterintuitive results arise. For example, it may benefit a global firm to transfer less technology for products with a higher emerging market potential. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc An analysis of coordination mechanisms for the U.S. cash supply chain / Milind Dawande in Management science, Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010)
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 553-570
Titre : An analysis of coordination mechanisms for the U.S. cash supply chain Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Milind Dawande, Auteur ; Mili Mehrotra, Auteur ; Vijay Mookerjee, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 553-570 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Cash supply chain Coordination Fit sorting Cross shipping Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : The overuse of its currency processing facilities by depository institutions (DIs) has motivated the Federal Reserve (Fed) to impose its new cash recirculation policy. This overuse is characterized by the practice of cross-shipping, where a DI both deposits and withdraws cash of the same denomination in the same business week in the same geographical area. Under the new policy, which came into effect July 2007, the Fed has imposed a recirculation fee on cross-shipped cash. The Fed intends to use this fee to induce DIs to effectively recirculate cash so that the societal cost of providing cash to the public is lowered. To examine the efficacy of this mechanism, we first characterize the social optimum and then analyze the response of DIs under a recirculation fee levied on cross-shipped cash. We show that neither a linear recirculation fee, which is the Fed's current practice, nor a more sophisticated nonlinear fee is sufficient to guarantee a socially optimal response from DIs. We then derive a fundamentally different mechanism that induces DIs to self-select the social optimum. Our mechanism incorporates a fairness adjustment that avoids penalizing DIs that recirculate their fair share of cash and rewards DIs that recirculate more than this amount. We demonstrate that the mechanism is easy to implement and tolerates a reasonable amount of imprecision in the problem parameters. We also discuss a concept of welfare-preserving redistribution wherein the Fed allows a group of DIs to reallocate (amongst themselves) their deposits and demand if such a possibility does not increase societal cost. Finally, we analyze the impact of incorporating the custodial inventory program, another component of the Fed's new policy. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] An analysis of coordination mechanisms for the U.S. cash supply chain [texte imprimé] / Milind Dawande, Auteur ; Mili Mehrotra, Auteur ; Vijay Mookerjee, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 553-570.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 553-570
Mots-clés : Cash supply chain Coordination Fit sorting Cross shipping Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : The overuse of its currency processing facilities by depository institutions (DIs) has motivated the Federal Reserve (Fed) to impose its new cash recirculation policy. This overuse is characterized by the practice of cross-shipping, where a DI both deposits and withdraws cash of the same denomination in the same business week in the same geographical area. Under the new policy, which came into effect July 2007, the Fed has imposed a recirculation fee on cross-shipped cash. The Fed intends to use this fee to induce DIs to effectively recirculate cash so that the societal cost of providing cash to the public is lowered. To examine the efficacy of this mechanism, we first characterize the social optimum and then analyze the response of DIs under a recirculation fee levied on cross-shipped cash. We show that neither a linear recirculation fee, which is the Fed's current practice, nor a more sophisticated nonlinear fee is sufficient to guarantee a socially optimal response from DIs. We then derive a fundamentally different mechanism that induces DIs to self-select the social optimum. Our mechanism incorporates a fairness adjustment that avoids penalizing DIs that recirculate their fair share of cash and rewards DIs that recirculate more than this amount. We demonstrate that the mechanism is easy to implement and tolerates a reasonable amount of imprecision in the problem parameters. We also discuss a concept of welfare-preserving redistribution wherein the Fed allows a group of DIs to reallocate (amongst themselves) their deposits and demand if such a possibility does not increase societal cost. Finally, we analyze the impact of incorporating the custodial inventory program, another component of the Fed's new policy. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc Competing manufacturers in a retail supply chain / Gérard P. Cachon in Management science, Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010)
[article]
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 571-589
Titre : Competing manufacturers in a retail supply chain : On contractual form and coordination Type de document : texte imprimé Auteurs : Gérard P. Cachon, Auteur ; Gürhan A. Kök, Auteur Année de publication : 2010 Article en page(s) : pp. 571-589 Note générale : Management Langues : Anglais (eng) Mots-clés : Contracting Competition Retailing Wholesale-price contract Quantity discount Two-part tariff Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : It is common for a retailer to sell products from competing manufacturers. How then should the firms manage their contract negotiations? The supply chain coordination literature focuses either on a single manufacturer selling to a single retailer or one manufacturer selling to many (possibly competing) retailers. We find that some key conclusions from those market structures do not apply in our setting, where multiple manufacturers sell through a single retailer. We allow the manufacturers to compete for the retailer's business using one of three types of contracts: a wholesale-price contract, a quantity-discount contract, or a two-part tariff. It is well known that the latter two, more sophisticated contracts enable the manufacturer to coordinate the supply chain, thereby maximizing the profits available to the firms. More importantly, they allow the manufacturer to extract rents from the retailer, in theory allowing the manufacturer to leave the retailer with only her reservation profit. However, we show that in our market structure these two sophisticated contracts force the manufacturers to compete more aggressively relative to when they only offer wholesale-price contracts, and this may leave them worse off and the retailer substantially better off. In other words, although in a serial supply chain a retailer may have just cause to fear quantity discounts and two-part tariffs, a retailer may actually prefer those contracts when offered by competing manufacturers. We conclude that the properties a contractual form exhibits in a one-manufacturer supply chain may not carry over to the realistic setting in which multiple manufacturers must compete to sell their goods through the same retailer. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc [article] Competing manufacturers in a retail supply chain : On contractual form and coordination [texte imprimé] / Gérard P. Cachon, Auteur ; Gürhan A. Kök, Auteur . - 2010 . - pp. 571-589.
Management
Langues : Anglais (eng)
in Management science > Vol. 56 N° 3 (Mars 2010) . - pp. 571-589
Mots-clés : Contracting Competition Retailing Wholesale-price contract Quantity discount Two-part tariff Index. décimale : 658 Organisation des entreprises. Techniques du commerce Résumé : It is common for a retailer to sell products from competing manufacturers. How then should the firms manage their contract negotiations? The supply chain coordination literature focuses either on a single manufacturer selling to a single retailer or one manufacturer selling to many (possibly competing) retailers. We find that some key conclusions from those market structures do not apply in our setting, where multiple manufacturers sell through a single retailer. We allow the manufacturers to compete for the retailer's business using one of three types of contracts: a wholesale-price contract, a quantity-discount contract, or a two-part tariff. It is well known that the latter two, more sophisticated contracts enable the manufacturer to coordinate the supply chain, thereby maximizing the profits available to the firms. More importantly, they allow the manufacturer to extract rents from the retailer, in theory allowing the manufacturer to leave the retailer with only her reservation profit. However, we show that in our market structure these two sophisticated contracts force the manufacturers to compete more aggressively relative to when they only offer wholesale-price contracts, and this may leave them worse off and the retailer substantially better off. In other words, although in a serial supply chain a retailer may have just cause to fear quantity discounts and two-part tariffs, a retailer may actually prefer those contracts when offered by competing manufacturers. We conclude that the properties a contractual form exhibits in a one-manufacturer supply chain may not carry over to the realistic setting in which multiple manufacturers must compete to sell their goods through the same retailer. DEWEY : 658 ISSN : 0025-1909 En ligne : http://mansci.journal.informs.org/content/56/3.toc
Exemplaires
Code-barres | Cote | Support | Localisation | Section | Disponibilité |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
aucun exemplaire |